Publications by Date

2007
Frankel J. Responding to Crises. Cato Journal [Internet]. 2007;27 (2) :165-178. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. World Trade and Payments: An Introduction by Richard Caves, Ronald Jones and Jeffrey Frankel. 10th ed. Boston: Addison Wesley Longman; 2007. WTP frontmatter i-xviii.pdf
2006
Frankel J. The Balassa-Samuelson Relationship and the Renminbi. KSG [Internet]. 2006. Publisher's Version
Frankel J, Romer D, Cyrus T. Trade and Growth in East Asian Countries: Cause and Effect?. NICs After Asian Crisis [Internet]. 2006;23. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. On the Yuan: The Choice Between Adjustment under a Fixed Exchange Rate and Adjustment under a Flexible Rate. CESifo Economic Studies (Oxford Univ. Press) [Internet]. 2006;52 (2) :246-275. Publisher's VersionAbstract

Fixed and flexible exchange rates each have advantages, and a country has the right to choose the regime suited to its circumstances. Nevertheless, several arguments support the view that the de facto dollar peg may now have outlived its usefulness for China. (i) Although foreign exchange reserves are a useful shield against currency crises, by now China's current level is fully adequate, and US treasury securities do not pay a high return. (ii) It may become increasingly difficult to sterilize the inflow over time. (iii) Although external balance could be achieved by expenditure reduction, e.g. by raising interest rates, the existence of two policy goals (external balance and internal balance) in general requires the use of two independent policy instruments (e.g. the real exchange rate and the interest rate). (iv) A large economy like China can achieve adjustment in the real exchange rate via flexibility in the nominal exchange rate more easily than via price flexibility. (v) The experience of other emerging markets points toward exiting from a peg when times are good and the currency is strong, rather than waiting until times are bad and the currency is under attack. (vi) From a longer-run perspective, prices of goods and services in China are low—not just low relative to the US (0.23), but also low by the standards of a Balassa–Samuelson relationship estimated across countries (which predicts 0.36). In this specific sense, the yuan was undervalued by ∼35 percent in 2000, and is by at least as much as that today. The study finds that, typically across countries, such gaps are corrected halfway, on average, over the subsequent decade. These six arguments for increased exchange rate flexibility need not imply a free float. China is a good counter-example to the popular “corners hypothesis” prohibition on intermediate exchange rate regimes. However, the specific changes announced by the Chinese authorities in July 2005 have not yet resulted in a de facto abandonment of the dollar peg.

on_the_yuan_proofs.pdf
Frankel J, Smit B, Sturzenegger F. Fiscal and Monetary Policy in a Commodity-Based Economy: Macroeconomic Challenges after a Decade of Success. Economics of Transition [Internet]. 2006;16 (4) :679-713. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. Could the Twin Deficits Jeopardize US Hegemony?. Twin Deficits, Growth and Stability of the US Economy [Internet]. 2006;28 (6) :653-663. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. Global Imbalances and Low Interest Rates: An Equilibrium Model vs. a Disequilibrium Reality, in BIS Annual Research Conference. Brunnen, Switzerland ; 2006. Publisher's VersionAbstract

The most obvious explanation for the large and widening US current account deficit is the high budget deficit and low national saving. But a variety of clever economists have come up with 8 other, more sanguine, explanations: (1) the siblings are not twins, (2) investment boom, (3) low US private savings, (4) global savings glut, (5) "It's a big world," (6) valuation effects will pay for it, (7) "Intermediation rents . . . pay for the trade deficits," and (8) China's development strategy entails accumulating unlimited dollars. The impressive paper by Caballero, Farhis, and Gourinchas falls under category (7). Their theoretical model is innovative and interesting, and has the virtue of being able to explain the current account deficit together with the anomalously low long-term interest rates during 2001-2005. The basic idea is that fast growth in emerging markets coupled with their inability to generate local store of value instruments increases their demand for saving instruments from the developed countries. More growth potential in the United States than in Europe means that a larger share of global saving flows to US assets. Ultimately, however, I am not sure that it is the correct explanation, or a reason to consider the deficits sustainable, any more than the others. Their hypothesized collapse in the desirability of emerging market assets and stagnant growth in Europe and Japan fit the 1990s fairly well. But they don't fit 2003-2006 as well, which is the puzzle period, that is, the period that featured the record US current account deficits coinciding with low long-term interest rates. Emerging markets have had a high capacity during 2003-06 to generate assets that others want. More persuasive is the hypothesis that the US continues to exploit the exorbitant privilege under which others accumulate dollars as reserves, but that this exclusive position of the dollar will not necessarily continue forever.

2005
Frankel J. Peg the Export Price Index: A Proposed Monetary Regime for Small Countries. Journal of Policy Modeling [Internet]. 2005;June. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. Climate and Trade: Links Between the Kyoto Protocol and WTO. Environment [Internet]. 2005;47 (7) :8-19. Link
Frankel J. The Environment and Globalization. In: Weinstein M Globalization: What's New. New York: Columbia University Press ; 2005. pp. 129-169. Link
Frankel J, Rose A. Is Trade Good or Bad for the Environment? Sorting out the Causality. Review of Economics and Statistics [Internet]. 2005;87 (1). Link
Frankel J. Comments on "The Euro's Trade Effects" by Richard Baldwin. [Internet]. 2005. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. Real Convergence and Euro Adoption in Central and Eastern Europe: Trade and Business Cycle Correlations as Endogenous Criteria for Joining EMU. Euro Adoption in the Accession Countries -- Opportunities and Challenges [Internet]. 2005. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. On the Tenge: Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy for Kazakhstan. [Internet]. 2005. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. Contractionary Currency Crashes in Developing Countries. IMF Staff Papers [Internet]. 2005;52 (2) :149-192. Publisher's VersionAbstract
To update an old statistic: a political leader in a developing country is almost twice as likely to lose office in the six months following a currency crash as otherwise. This difference, which is highly significant statistically, holds regardless of whether the devaluation takes place in the context of an IMF program. Why are devaluations so costly? Many of the currency crises of the last 10 years have been associated with output loss. Is this, as alleged, because of excessive reliance on raising the interest rate as a policy response? More likely it is because of contractionary effects of devaluation. There are various possible contractionary effects of devaluation, but it is appropriate that the balance sheet effect receives the most emphasis. Pass-through from exchange rate changes to import prices in developing countries is not the problem: this coefficient fell in the 1990s, as a look at some narrowly defined products shows. Rather, balance sheets are the problem. How can countries mitigate the fall in output resulting from the balance sheet effect in crises? In the shorter term, adjusting promptly after inflows cease is better than procrastinating by shifting to short-term dollar debt, which raises the costliness of the devaluation when it finally comes. In the longer term, greater openness to trade reduces vulnerability to both sudden stops and currency crashes.
Frankel J, Wei S-J. Managing Macroeconomic Crises: Policy Lessons. Managing Economic Volatility and Crises: A Practitioner's Guide [Internet]. 2005. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. Contractionary Currency Crashes in Developing Countries. NBER Working Paper Series [Internet]. 2005;52 (2) :149-192. Publisher's VersionAbstract
To update an old statistic: a political leader in a developing country is almost twice as likely to lose office in the six months following a currency crash as otherwise. This difference, which is highly significant statistically, holds regardless of whether the devaluation takes place in the context of an IMF program. Why are devaluations so costly? Many of the currency crises of the last 10 years have been associated with output loss. Is this, as alleged, because of excessive reliance on raising the interest rate as a policy response? More likely it is because of contractionary effects of devaluation. There are various possible contractionary effects of devaluation, but it is appropriate that the balance sheet effect receives the most emphasis. Pass-through from exchange rate changes to import prices in developing countries is not the problem: this coefficient fell in the 1990s, as a look at some narrowly defined products shows. Rather, balance sheets are the problem. How can countries mitigate the fall in output resulting from the balance sheet effect in crises? In the shorter term, adjusting promptly after inflows cease is better than procrastinating by shifting to short-term dollar debt, which raises the costliness of the devaluation when it finally comes. In the longer term, greater openness to trade reduces vulnerability to both sudden stops and currency crashes.
rwp_05_017_frankel.pdf
Frankel J. On the Renminbi. CESifo Forum [Internet]. 2005;6 (3) :16-21. Publisher's Version
Frankel J. What's Ahead: Decade of the Dollar, the Euro, or the RMB?. 2005. athensdecadeeurormb-j.doc

Pages