Publications

Web Article
Glaeser EL, Scheinkman JA, Shleifer A. The Injustice of Inequality. 2002. PDF
Glaeser EL, Shapiro JM. The Benefits of the Home Mortgage Interest Deduction. 2002. PDF
Glaeser EL. Does Rent Control Reduce Segregation?. 2002. PDF
Glaeser EL, Shleifer A. Legal Origins. 2001. PDF
Glaeser EL, Shapiro J. Is There a New Urbanism? The Growth of U.S. Cities in the 1990s. 2001. PDF
Glaeser EL. Public Ownership in the American City. 2001. PDF
Glaeser EL. The Economics of Location-Based Tax Incentives. 2001. PDF
Alesina A, Glaeser EL, Sacerdote B. Why Doesn't the U.S. Have a European-Style Welfare State?. 2001. PDF
Glaeser EL, Shapiro JM. Cities and Warfare: The Impact of Terrorism on Urban Form. 2001. PDF
Glaeser EL, Kahn ME, Rappaport J. Why Do The Poor Live In Cities?. 2000. PDF
Glaeser EL, Sacerdote B. The Determinants of Punishment: Deterrence, Incapacitation and Vengeance. 2000. PDF
Glaeser EL, Kolko J, Saiz A. Consumer City. 2000. PDF
Journal Article
Abbiasov T, Heine C, Glaeser EL, Ratti C, Sabouri S, Miranda AS, Santi P. The 15-Minute City Quantified Using Mobility Data. NBER Working Paper No, w30752. Working Paper. Publisher's VersionAbstract
Americans travel 7 to 9 miles on average for shopping and recreational activities, which is far longer than the 15-minute (walking) city advocated by ecologically-oriented urban planners. This paper provides a comprehensive analysis of local trip behavior in US cities using GPS data on individual trips from 40 million mobile devices. We define local usage as the share of trips made within 15-minutes walking distance from home, and find that the median US city resident makes only 12% of their daily trips within such a short distance. We find that differences in access to local services can explain eighty percent of the variation in 15-minute usage across metropolitan areas and 74 percent of the variation in usage within metropolitan areas. Differences in historic zoning permissiveness within New York suggest a causal link between access and usage, and that less restrictive zoning rules, such as permitting more mixed-use development, would lead to shorter travel times. Finally, we document a strong correlation between local usage and experienced segregation for poorer, but not richer, urbanites, which suggests that 15-minute cities may also exacerbate the social isolation of marginalized communities.
Cutler DM, Glaeser EL. When Innovation Goes Wrong: Technological Regress and the Opioid Epidemic. National Bureau of Economics . 2021. Publisher's VersionAbstract
The fivefold increase in opioid deaths between 2000 and 2017 rivals even the COVID-19 pandemic as a health crisis for America. Why did it happen? Measures of demand for pain relief – physical pain and despair – are high but largely unchanging. The primary shift is in supply, primarily of new forms of allegedly safer narcotics. These new pain relievers flowed mostly to areas with more pain, but since their apparent safety was an illusion, opioid deaths followed. By the end of the 2000s, restrictions on legal opioids led to further supply-side innovations which created the burgeoning illegal market that accounts for the bulk of opioid deaths today. Because opioid use is easier to start than end, America’s opioid epidemic is likely to persist for some time.
wheninnovtationgoeswrongtechnologicalregress.pdf
Behrer AP, Glaeser EL, Ponzetto GAM, Shleifer A. Securing Property Rights. Journal of Political Economy. 2021;129 (4). Publisher's VersionAbstract
A central challenge in securing property rights is the subversion of justice. We present a model of a polluter whose discharges harm multiple owners, and we compare property rules, liability rules, and regulation on efficiency grounds. We provide conditions under which property rules are preferred to liability rules, thus verifying the Calabresi-Melamed conjecture. Regulation that enforces partial abatement may be preferred to either of the extreme rules. An empirical analysis of water quality in the United States before and after the Clean Water Act shows that the effects of regulation are consistent with several predictions of the model.
securingpropertyrights.pdf
Djankov S, Glaeser EL, Perotti V, Schleifer A. Property Rights and Urban Form. National Bureau of Economic Research. 2021. Publisher's VersionAbstract
How do the different elements in the standard bundle of property rights, including those of possession and transfer, influence the shape of cities? This paper incorporates insecure property rights into a standard model of urban land prices and density, and makes predictions about investment in land and property, informality, and the efficiency of land use. Our empirical analysis links data on institutions for land titling and transfer with multiple urban outcomes, in 190 countries. The evidence is generally consistent with the model’s predictions, and more broadly with the Demsetz’s (1967) approach to property rights institutions. Indeed, we document world-wide improvements in the quality of institutions facilitating property transfer over time.
property_rights_urban_form_nberwp_2021_0505.pdf
Glaeser EL, Luca M, Moszkowski E. Gentrification and Neighborhood Change: Evidence From Yelp. National Bureau of Economic Research. 2020. Publisher's VersionAbstract
How does gentrification transform neighborhoods? Gentrification can harm current residents by increasing rental costs and by eliminating old amenities, including distinctive local stores. Rising rents represent redistribution from tenants to landlords and can therefore be offset with targeted transfers, but the destruction of neighborhood character can – in principle – reduce overall social surplus. Using Census and Yelp data from five cities, we document that while gentrification is associated with an increase in the number of retail establishments overall, it is also associated with higher rates of business closure and higher rates of transition to higher price points. In Chicago and Los Angeles especially, non-gentrifying poorer communities have dramatically lower turnover than richer or gentrifying communities. However, the primary transitions appear to the replacement of stores that sell tradable goods with stores that sell non-tradable services. That transition just seems to be slower in poor communities that do not gentrify. Consequently, the business closures that come with gentrification seem to reflect the global impact of electronic commerce more than the replacement of idiosyncratic neighborhood services with generic luxury goods.
gentrificationandneighborhoodchangeyelp.pdf
Glaeser EL, Poterba JM. Economic Analysis and Infrastructure Investment. National Bureau of Economic Resarch. 2020. Publisher's VersionAbstract
This paper summarizes economic research on investment in public infrastructure and introduces the findings of several new studies on this topic. It begins with a review of several potential justifications for the public sector’s involvement in building, financing, and operating infrastructure, including limitations of private capital markets, externalities, and the control of natural monopolies. It then describes the conditions that characterize an optimal infrastructure investment program, emphasizing the need to extend project-based microeconomic cost-benefit analysis to incorporate the value of economy-wide macroeconomic and other externalities. It notes the importance of efficient use of infrastructure capital, and discusses three areas – procurement, project management, and expenditure on externality mitigation – where further research could identify paths to efficiency improvement. It concludes by identifying several trends that have emerged since outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic that may have long-term effects on the role of both physical and digital infrastructure in the U.S. economy.
economicanalysisandinfrastructureinvestment.pdf
Glaeser EL. Urbanization and Its Discontents. National Bureau of Economic Research. 2019. Publisher's VersionAbstract
American cities have experienced a remarkable renaissance over the past 40 years, but in recent years, cities have experienced considerable discontent. Anger about high housing prices and gentrification has led to protests. The urban wage premium appears to have disappeared for less skilled workers. The cities of the developing world are growing particularly rapidly, but in those places, the downsides of density are acute. In this essay, I review the causes of urban discontent and present a unified explanation for this unhappiness. Urban resurgence represents private sector success, and the public sector typically only catches up to urban change with a considerable lag. Moreover, as urban machines have been replaced by governments that are more accountable to empowered residents, urban governments do more to protect insiders and less to enable growth. The power of insiders can be seen in the regulatory limits on new construction and new businesses, the slow pace of school reform and the unwillingness to embrace congestion pricing.
urbanization_and_its_discontents_final.pdf
Chen J, Glaeser EL, Wessel D. The (Non-)Effect of Opportunity Zones on Housing Prices. National Bureau of Economic Research. 2019. Publisher's VersionAbstract
Will the Opportunity Zone program, America’s largest new place-based policy in decades, generate neighborhood change? We compare single-family housing price growth in Opportunity Zones with price growth in areas that were eligible but not included in the program. We also compare Opportunity Zones to their nearest geographic neighbors. All estimates rule out price impacts greater than 1.3 percentage points with 95% confidence, suggesting that, so far, home buyers don’t believe that this subsidy will generate major neighborhood change. Opportunity Zone status reduces prices in areas with little employment, perhaps because buyers think that subsidizing new investment will increase housing supply.
non-effect_oppor_zones_on_housing_nberwp_2019_1216.pdf

Pages